18,99 €
Social relations are crucial for understanding diverse economic actions and a network perspective is central to that explanation. Simple exchanges involving money, labor, and commodities combine into complexly connected systems. Economic networks span many levels of analysis, from persons (consumers, employees), to groups (households, workteams), organizations (corporations, interest groups), populations (industries, markets) and the rapidly expanding global economic system. David Knoke blends network theories from a range of disciplines and empirical studies of domestic and international economies to illuminate how economic activity is embedded in and constrained by social ties among economic actors. Social capital, in the form of connections to others holding valuable resources, is vital for finding a job, buying a car, creating a new industry, or triggering a global financial crisis. In nontechnical terms the author explicates the core network concepts, measures, and analysis methods behind these phenomena. The book also includes many striking network diagrams to provide visual insights into complex structural patterns. This accessible book offers an invaluable critique for both undergraduate and graduate students in economic sociology and social network analysis courses who seek a better understanding of the multifaceted economic webs in which we are all entangled.
Sie lesen das E-Book in den Legimi-Apps auf:
Seitenzahl: 366
Veröffentlichungsjahr: 2014
Markets, Patrik Aspers
Economy and State, Nina Bandelj and Elizabeth SowersMoney and Credit, Bruce G. Carruthers and Laura AriovichGlobal Capitalism, Miguel A. Centeno and Joseph Nathan CohenInstitutions and the Economy, Francesco Duina
Economic Networks, David Knoke
polity
For Felix, grandson extraordinaire
But the truth, even more, is that life is perpetually weaving fresh threads which link one individual and one event to another, and that these threads are crossed and recrossed, doubled and redoubled to thicken the web, so that between any slightest point of our past and all the others a rich network of memories gives us an almost infinite variety of communicating paths to choose from.
Marcel Proust
Time Regained (1927)
Economic network analysis grew almost exponentially over the past three decades, spurred by the revival of economic sociology and belated interest in networks by some mainstream economists. It benefited from general improvements in network data collection and methods for analyzing them. Most importantly, the quality of explanation and understanding of economic action as both cause and consequence of relations among social actors greatly advanced. This book assesses and interprets diverse economic behaviors from a network perspective. It blends theoretical explanations about structural relations among economic actors – persons and organizations – with empirical evidence from network research on domestic and international economies. Its central themes are: economic actions are embedded in, and are explained by, the social connections among actors; an actor’s social capital consists of others’ resources that can be accessed by the actor; and benefits and costs within economic systems are jointly determined and constrained by the network ties among participants.
The six chapters examine economic networks spanning levels of analysis from individuals, to teams and firms, to markets and interorganizational systems, to the global economy. I strive to explicate core network concepts, measures, and analysis methods in nontechnical terms. Several network diagrams convey visual insights into complex structural patterns. The primary audiences are undergraduate and graduate students taking courses in economic sociology, organizational studies, and social network analysis. The book draws heavily from my experiences in teaching those courses during the past quarter century at the University of Minnesota. I thank the many students from diverse disciplines who participated enthusiastically and contributed in numerous ways that helped me to become a better teacher and scholar. I also thank two anonymous reviewers, Jonathan Skerrett, and Lauren Mulholland at Polity for their invaluable assistance in bringing the project to fruition.
David Knoke
Minneapolis, Minnesota
January 18, 2012
On April 20, 2010, the Deepwater Horizon – a gigantic rig leased by BP plc to drill its exploratory Macondo Prospect oil well 50 miles off the coast of Louisiana – exploded, killing 11 workers and injuring 17 others before sinking a mile deep into the Gulf of Mexico. As much as five million gallons of oil spewed from the borehole before two relief wells plugged it four months later. The spill contaminated coastal marshes and beaches, killed untold numbers of birds and sea turtles, wreaked havoc on four state economies, and further eroded President Barack Obama’s public support. Even before a presidential commission finished investigating the nation’s worst environmental disaster, evidence quickly surfaced about a tangled web of incompetence, criminality, and collective delusions by BP and the regulatory agency charged with overseeing the oil and gas industry. The Bush Administration had allowed the industry to write its own regulatory rules, scrapped environmental impact reviews, and fast-tracked drilling permits. The Interior Department’s Minerals Management Service (MMS) had a structural conflict of interest: it collected royalty payments from the very companies it was supposed to regulate. MMS let oil firms regulate themselves; for example, BP employees penciled in report forms for inspectors to trace over in ink and sign. In 2008, MMS granted BP, a corporation implicated in all major oil disasters beginning with the 1989 Exxon Valdez spill, an exemption from submitting an emergency plan for deepwater blowouts. Instead, BP submitted a “regional plan” to deal with general spills anywhere in the Gulf. Despite the Obama Administration’s reform rhetoric, business continued as usual under the new Interior Secretary, Ken Salazar, who failed to remove many long-serving MMS bureaucrats. Just two months after he took office, MMS approved BP’s Deepwater Horizon well application, which consisted of boilerplate apparently copied from an Arctic drilling plan (it mentioned walruses and other cold-water sea mammals). The plan contained neither discussions of potential deepwater blowouts, nor any site-specific plans to respond to a spill (Dickinson 2010). BP cut many safety corners at Deepwater Horizon, most notoriously in deploying a blowout preventer without a remote-control trigger. When a series of human and technological errors culminated in the April explosion, BP had neither effective means to shut off the flow nor to mop up its impact.
Behind this farce turned tragedy lay a social network explanation, the cozy connections between regulatory agents and corporate employees that skirted ethics and violated laws. Just weeks before Deepwater Horizon exploded, the US Interior Department’s Office of Inspector General completed a report on MMS corruption between 2005 and 2007. It found a flourishing culture of corruption and criminality. Employees watched porn, used coke and crystal meth, accepted gifts, travel, and sports tickets from oil and gas companies. “When agency staffers weren’t joining industry employees for coke parties or trips to corporate ski chalets, they were having sex with oil-company officials” (Dickinson 2010). One MMS employee “conducted four inspections on drilling platforms when he was also negotiating a job with the drilling company” (Urbina 2010). Bureaucrats at the Lake Charles MMS office repeatedly went on hunting and fishing trips with employees of the Island Operating Company, whose Gulf drilling platforms they regulated. When investigators showed Lake Charles District Manager Larry Williamson photos of two inspectors at a 2005 Peach Bowl game tailgate party paid for by Island Operating, he explained:
Obviously, we’re all oil industry. We’re all from the same part of the country. Almost all our inspectors have worked for oil companies out of these same platforms. They grew up in the same towns. Some of these people, they’ve been friends with all their life. They’ve been with these people since they were kids. They’ve hunted together. They fish together. They skeet shoot together … They do this all the time. (Office of Inspector General 2010: 3)
A revolving-door phenomenon, also known as regulatory agency capture, emerged as early as the nineteenth century in the canal and railroad industries (Levine and Florence 1990). The failure of agencies to act on behalf of the public interest, but instead serving special interests, is prevalent in the federal and state governments. One common capture mechanism, exemplified by MMS negligence preceding the Gulf oil spill, is the web of interpersonal ties spun among personnel routinely flowing between agencies and corporations. Also relevant is “cognitive capture,” a consensual taken-for-granted mindset emerging among people who share numerous formative experiences, which can blinker them to looming dangers and alternative solutions.
This introductory chapter provides brief and broad sketches of mainstream and heterodox economics, economic sociology, and social network theories that set the contexts for more detailed examinations of economic networks in subsequent chapters. Readers interested in learning more about broader debates within economics and economic sociology should consult the huge primary literatures of those disciplines. The Appendix lists sources for instruction, software programs, and datasets for further self-study. Economic networks operate at multiple levels of analysis, including individuals (consumers, employees), groups (households, work teams), organizations (firms, interest groups), and populations (industries, markets), as well as across these levels. An important goal for this book is to develop concepts and principles useful for understanding complex economic relations.
Mainstream and Alternative Economic Theories
This section summarizes the core assumptions and principles of mainstream economic theory and its application to actors and markets. A discipline’s mainstream “consists of the ideas that are held by those individuals who are dominant in the leading academic institutions, organizations, and journals at any given time, especially the leading graduate research institutions. Mainstream economics consists of the ideas that the elite in the profession finds acceptable, where by ‘elite’ we mean the leading economists in the top graduate schools” (Colander et al. 2004: 490). After describing the neoclassical synthesis that dominates mainstream economics, I briefly review some critiques and describe some alternative theories proposed by heterodox economists seeking to diversify the dominant paradigm. These developments prepare the stage for the economic sociology and social network approaches discussed in subsequent sections.
Mainstream Economic Theory
The dominant paradigm of mainstream economists originated in the neoclassical theories of late nineteenth-century economists, who built on the ideas of such classical founders as Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and John Stuart Mill. Among the key contributions of neoclassical economists – including William Stanley Jevons, Carl Menger, Léon Walras, and Alfred Marshall – were general equilibrium, marginal analysis, and price theory. By the middle of the twentieth century, a neoclassical synthesis, combining neoclassical microeconomics with the macroeconomic approach of John Maynard Keynes, became the mainstream economic theory presently taught to generations of countless undergraduates in introductory economics courses. Mainstream economic theory encompasses decision making at both micro- (individuals, firms) and macro- (markets, industries, whole economies) levels of analysis to explain the production, exchange, and consumption of economic goods and services. Key components include rational actors, independence of decision making, and utility maximization. In simplified terms, the core assumptions of mainstream economic theory are:
Mainstream economic theory’s simplifying assumptions enable modern economists to apply powerful deductive methods to its axioms, specify elegant systems of mathematical equations, and apply sophisticated statistical procedures to empirical data to generate precise predictions and forecasts about economic activity. Consequently, economists have become highly influential in shaping a wide range of public policies affecting individuals, families, firms, and industries. However, hosts of critics inside and outside the discipline raised doubts about the realism, validity, and accuracy of mainstream economic theory as both explanation of economic action and guide to policymakers.
Criticism and Rebuttal
A persistent criticism, voiced principally by economists themselves, is that the core assumptions of the neoclassical synthesis vastly oversimplify economic reality, and hence provide a shaky foundation on which to construct accurate theoretical explanations of empirical observations (e.g., Rappaport 1996). For example, Geoffrey Hodgson argued that mainstream theory “is steeped in the metaphors and presuppositions of classical physics,” creating “an artificial world where time is reversible, where individuals are self-contained, atomistic units, and where both extreme complexity and chronic problems of information and knowledge are excluded. The idea of rational, maximizing actors interacting and reaching an equilibrium is modeled precisely in these mechanistic terms” (Hodgson 1992: 757). Similarly, Steve Keen (2001) cataloged numerous instances where mainstream theoretical premises are either inconsistent or lack empirical evidence. For example, Keen and Standish (2006) argued that Alfred Marshall’s assumption that firms in a perfectly competitive industry do not react strategically to one another’s actions is demonstrably false. “As a consequence, the Marshallian model of atomistic behavior leads to industry output being independent of the number of firms in it, in contradiction of standard neoclassical pedagogy and belief” (p. 82). Other critics complained that mainstream economists grew too reliant on simplifying assumptions because they permit tractable estimates of complex mathematical models.
Milton Friedman, in his famous 1953 essay, “The Methodology of Positive Economics,” defended the epistemological bases of mainstream economic theory against the complaint of unrealism. Mainstream theory is an ideal type that isolates crucial features of a particular economic problem, and is not intended to be descriptively accurate. Whether businessmen really make their decisions by rationally calculating marginal costs and revenues, and seek to maximize utility in every economic transaction, is irrelevant. Instead, Friedman argued, the theory hypothesizes only that, over a wide range of economic situations, people and firms behave
as if they were seeking rationally to maximize their expected returns (generally if misleadingly called “profits”) and had full knowledge of the data needed to succeed in this attempt; as if, that is, they knew the relevant cost and demand functions, calculated marginal cost and marginal revenue from all actions open to them, and pushed each line of action to the point at which the relevant marginal cost and marginal revenue were equal. (Friedman 1970: 21–22)
The ultimate criterion for judging a theory’s usefulness lies, not in the realism of its untestable assumptions, but in its simplicity in making precise predictions about observable economic phenomena of broad scope. Friedman concluded that mainstream theory makes demonstrably superior economic predictions, in comparison to alternative theories which all produce inferior predictions.
If predictive accuracy is the criterion for judging theory, then mainstream economic theory did a very poor job of anticipating and explaining recent speculative bubbles and busts, particularly the high-tech or dot.com bubble of 1998–2000 and the Global Financial Crisis of 2007–9. Mainstream finance economists proposed an efficient markets hypothesis: because stock prices and other financial assets reflect complete economic information, investors always have realistic expectations about future prices and hence will act rationally. Irrational beliefs and actions, such as betting on continually rising stock and housing prices, could never occur because financial markets are self-regulating, and, thus, require no interference or constraints by government. But, by excluding bankers and investment institutions from their simplified economic model, mainstream economists ignored the possibility that both lenders and consumers could lack complete information and might inaccurately assess the high risks of buying and selling the complex securitized mortgage bundles which inflated an enormous subprime-mortgage bubble. Mainstream economists “turned a blind eye to the limitations of human rationality that often lead to bubbles and busts; to the problems of institutions that run amok; to the imperfections of markets – especially financial markets – that can cause the economy’s operating system to undergo sudden, unpredictable crashes; and to the dangers created when regulators don’t believe in regulation” (Krugman 2009: 2). Chapter 5 examines the social relations that exacerbated the 2007–9 Global Financial Crisis.
Alternative Economic Theories
Challenges to mainstream economic theory arose throughout the discipline’s development. Nonmainstream, or heterodox, theories make diverse assumptions that are incompatible with mainstream conceptualizations of economic actors and markets (Colander et al. 2004). In rough order of their historical emergence:
The preceding summaries of mainstream economic theory and its heterodox challengers reveal substantial disagreement and intellectual ferment. Some observers perceived unprecedented opportunities for alternative approaches to move from the discipline’s periphery toward the center where transcendent syntheses might occur (Colander et al. 2004). Others saw mainstream economics as deeply entrenched and resistant to change (Hodgson 2007). With no fully integrated alternative theory to the neoclassical synthesis yet at hand, the prospects for the radical transformation of mainstream economics appear dim. “None of these is at present strong enough or complete enough to declare itself a contender for the title of ‘the’ economic theory of the 21st century” (Keen 2001).
A few economists grew more receptive over the past two decades to using network ideas and methods to explain economic behaviors. Some challenged mainstream economics to develop network theories and methods to improve understanding of global economic interdependencies and reduce the risks of catastrophic failures: “We need, therefore, an approach that stresses the systemic complexity of economic networks and that can be used to revise and extend established paradigms in economic theory” (Schweitzer et al. 2009: 422). Matthew Jackson was possibly the earliest and most persistent advocate, exploring stylized models of network stability and efficiency (Jackson and Wolinsky 1996), network evolution (Jackson and Watts 2002), and labor markets (Calvó-Armengol and Jackson 2007). His methodological tome, Social and Economic Networks (Jackson 2008), drew heavily from sociology, game theory, computer science, and physics to illustrate analytic techniques and exemplify substantive research. Adalbert Mayer (2009) argued that economists take a distinctive approach to modeling social networks that emphasizes the role of choices under constraints, for example, in educational attainment and matching workers to jobs. Nevertheless, Nobel laureate Kenneth Arrow succinctly expressed the prevailing skepticism of many mainstream economists: “Network theory has been imported into economics as a tool, although it may not be all that useful or needed” (Arrow 2009: 14). The economic sociology perspective discussed in the next section can best be seen as yet another challenger to mainstream economic orthodoxy.
The Economic Sociology Perspective
This section sketches a history of economic sociology and summarizes some core principles of the new economic sociology that emerged over the past three decades. This overview provides the context for a more detailed examination of social network perspectives on economic activity in the following section.
A Brief History
Although an economist, William Jevons, first used the term “economic sociology” (Jevons 1965 [1879]: xvi; see Swedberg 2003: 5), it was quickly appropriated by several founders of classical sociology – including Max Weber, Émile Durkheim, and Georg Simmel – for their investigations of the great eighteenth- and nineteenth-century transformations from agrarian to industrial society, typified as the transition from community (Gemeinschaft) to association (Gesellschaft). Weber’s distinctly sociological understanding of the economy still provokes lively debate a century later, with some scholars viewing him as increasingly relevant today (e.g., Swedberg 1998; Parsons 2006), while others are skeptical that he truly transcended neoclassical conceptualizations of rationality and utility maximization (e.g., Peukert 2004). Ironically, Weber never held a professorship in sociology, but was an economics professor in the 1890s at Freiberg and Heidelberg universities before mental problems forced him to become a private scholar. However, he briefly headed a new institute of sociology at the University of Munich shortly before his death in 1920. Weber’s typology of action, as applied to economic behavior, is explicated below among the core principles of contemporary economic sociology. Durkheim’s main contribution to classical economic sociology, in The Division of Labor in Society, was a functionalist argument: strong collective consciousness norms are necessary to overcome tendencies toward economic anomie arising from the pursuit of self-interest in modern, highly differentiated societies. He advocated the creation of occupational corporations – associations of professions and crafts – where participants could thrive in “a warmth that quickens or gives fresh life to each individual, which makes him disposed to empathize, causing selfishness to melt away” (Durkheim 1984 [1893]: lii). Simmel, in The Web of Group Affiliations 1955 [1922], influenced the subsequent development of social network analysis through his investigations of dyadic and triadic forms of group structure (see chapter 3). Other contributors to classical economic sociology include heterodox economists Thorstein Veblen, Karl Marx, and Joseph Schumpeter, briefly discussed above, as well as Vilfredo Pareto who influenced the economic sociology of Talcott Parsons.
After its classical flowering, economic sociology experienced two notable developmental phases. Between the 1930s and 1960s, Parsons developed his general structural-functionalist “action theory” of society involving four subsystems, one of which is the adaptive subsystem or economy (A), which interchanges with the political (G), integrative (I), and cultural-motivational (L) subsystems to achieve overall societal development and coordination (Parsons 1951). In Economy and Society (1956), Parsons and Neil Smelser further developed the AGIL framework, theorized about the generalized media of exchange between each subsystem, and appealed for economists and sociologists to collaborate on a grand socioeconomic theoretical synthesis. Obviously, their call to action was ignored by both disciplines. In its most recent phase, beginning in the 1980s in the US, economic sociology revived through a convergence of neoinstitutionalism, cultural, and social network perspectives on economic phenomena (Convert and Heilbron 2007). Mark Granovetter’s manifesto (1985) and later programmatic statements (1992, 2002, 2005a) challenged sociologists to supplant both the neoclassical synthesis in economics and the old economic sociology with a distinctively contemporary social action theory. Components for an ambitious imperialistic agenda include socially constructed economic institutions, economic action embedded in social relations, and integration of culture and economics. The next subsection explicates core principles of the new economic sociology.
Core Principles
A serviceable definition of the new economic sociology is the use of sociological ideas to analyze economic phenomena: “the application of frames of reference, variables, and explanatory models of sociology to that complex of activities which is concerned with the production, distribution, exchange, and consumption of scarce goods and services” (Smelser and Swedberg 2005: 3). Economic sociology morphed into a “strange other” that is dissimilar to both sociology and economics (Finch 2007: 124). In contrast to mainstream economics, the discipline of sociology never had a dominant theoretical tradition comparable to the neoclassical synthesis. Absent any sociological mainstream, economic sociologists eclectically borrowed and freely adapted the principles, concepts, and theories of diverse specialties, including organization studies, political sociology, sociology of work, culture, historical-comparative research, and social network analysis. Economic sociology maintains affinities to several heterodox economics theories discussed above, especially Marxist economics, old institutional economics, and the Austrian School (Mikl-Horke 2008). Among these heterogeneous roots, a few core elements of the new economic sociology may be discerned:
Economic sociology is far less formalized and mathematical compared to mainstream economics’ emphasis on the rigorous quantification of economic transactions. Consequently, economic sociology theory is less capable of generating precise testable hypotheses. Its analysts are more disposed toward discursive historical-comparative, ethnographic, and thick narrative description of socioeconomic phenomena. However, as discussed next, social network analysis applies a quite rigorous methodology to examine structural patterns in economic relations.
The Social Network Perspective
Social network analysis is a multidisciplinary perspective in which structural relations among social actors are core explanatory concepts and principles. The web of ties among actors in a social system comprises the larger contexts that affect the perceptions, beliefs, attitudes, and actions of individuals and groups. Social influence and collective action may be both facilitated and constrained by direct and indirect transactions among actors possessing diverse resources, such as information, money, authority, and power. Network analysts view social actors as highly interdependent decision makers whose preferences and behaviors mutually influence one another to varying degrees through their network connections. By engaging in micro-level dyadic and triadic transactions, whether exchanging economic services or bodily fluids, actors collectively generate the macro-level sociospatial contexts within which all are embedded. In turn, these network structures may impede or assist subsequent transactions. Furthermore, network structures are themselves the result of dynamic processes, changing continuously over time as actors form new relations or drop old ties, enter or leave the system. Social network analysts seek to identify specific mechanisms through which social influence transpires and social structure evolves. Used in conjunction with neoinstitutionalism and resource dependence theories, network analysis reveals how rules and regulations gain acceptance and legitimacy within a population; how conformity to social norms is enforced and deviant behaviors penalized; and how information, ideas, and innovations diffuse or dissipate. In short, social network analysis captures the complex interactions that collectively constitute ongoing social systems.
In emphasizing relations among actors as basic units of analysis, social network theory diverges sharply from predominant substantialist explanations, which treat an actor’s attitudes and attributes, such as gender and race, as the basic units. Many sociologists depict “individuals as self-propelling, self-subsistent entities that pursue internalized norms given in advance and fixed for the duration of the action sequence under investigation” Emirbayer 1997: 284). Other sociologists take a “variable-centered approach” in which fixed entities with attribute variables cause outcomes that are also measured as attributes (or, as the Nowhere Man pithily put it in Yellow Submarine, “causes of causal causation”). Similarly, in mainstream economics and game theory, the self-interested rational actor chooses the alternative that maximizes personal utility, independently of any other actor’s choices. Social network analysts reject such atomized, noncontextual approaches in favor of structural-relational explanations that take into account the embeddedness of actors and their actions in concrete connections.