Ego - Frank Schirrmacher - E-Book

Ego E-Book

Frank Schirrmacher

0,0
11,99 €

-100%
Sammeln Sie Punkte in unserem Gutscheinprogramm und kaufen Sie E-Books und Hörbücher mit bis zu 100% Rabatt.
Mehr erfahren.
Beschreibung

Twenty-five years after the end of the Cold War, a new Cold War is being waged in our societies. During the Cold War a theoretical model of man was developed by economists and the military, an egotistical being interested only in his own benefit and in duping his opponents to achieve his ends: a modern homo oeconomicus. After his career in the Cold War ended, he was not scrapped but adapted to the needs of the twenty-first century. He became the ringmaster of a new era of information capitalism. He sought to read, control and influence thoughts; to predict, price and eliminate risks. Today stock-market trading is guided by him. He uses computer algorithms and Big Data to build up detailed pictures of our preferences and then suggest and sell goods to us. The model has become a self-fulfilling prophecy. We are no longer the masters of our own fate. The Game of Life runs without us. Schirrmacher traces the progress of this extreme rationalization of social life from the Cold War games of the 1950s Rand Corporation to the stock-market trading techniques that brought about the financial crash of 2008, showing how these developments were interwoven with the rise of game theory, rational choice theory and neoliberal economics. The state and politics increasingly submitted themselves to the logic of computerized game theory and an economistic view of the world, evading real decision-making in the process. In this brave new world individuals, alone in front of their computers, may think they are constructing a reality of their own choosing, but in fact they are being manipulated all along by others who are setting the rules of the game. This international bestseller by one of Germany s most distinguished journalists is a powerful indictment of a way of thinking that has become pervasive and threatens to undermine not only parliaments and constitutions but also the sovereignty of the individual to be the person he or she wants to be.

Sie lesen das E-Book in den Legimi-Apps auf:

Android
iOS
von Legimi
zertifizierten E-Readern

Seitenzahl: 394

Bewertungen
0,0
0
0
0
0
0
Mehr Informationen
Mehr Informationen
Legimi prüft nicht, ob Rezensionen von Nutzern stammen, die den betreffenden Titel tatsächlich gekauft oder gelesen/gehört haben. Wir entfernen aber gefälschte Rezensionen.



CONTENTS

Cover

Dedication

Title Page

Copyright

Preface

Notes

Part I Optimization of the game

1 Trance

The Military Seeks an Answer to the Question of How One Acts Egotistically

Notes

2 Game

Economists Give an Answer

Notes

3 Prophecy

The Truth is What we Believe

Notes

4 Monsters

Everyone Acts Rationally and Suddenly Monsters Appear

Notes

5 Screenplay

‘I Hope it Works’ – Crisis as Film

First: The Monster

Second: Mad Scientists

Third: The Monster Slayers

The Screenplay

Notes

6 Reason

We Become the Managers of Our Own Selves

Notes

7 Social physics

Mr Pimbley Gives a Speech and Advises Physicists to Dress Up for Wall Street

Notes

8 Massacre

Greed and Fear Will Suffice as Motivations for the Game of Life

Notes

9 Blood circulation

Inside the Machine Everything the Machine Does Becomes a Natural Law

Notes

10 Nervous system

For the First Time it’s Clear: We Don’t Need a Body to Act in the World, Just Strong Nerves

Notes

11 Android

Hardly have the First Automatons Been Assembled Than Humans are Dismantled

Notes

12 Brain

Humans Become Machine-Friendly

Notes

13 Genes

Egoism Conquers the Genome

Notes

14 Kinship

Even Nature Calculates Like a Stock Exchange Trader

Notes

15 Schizophrenia

The World is Much More Suited to Egotistical Automatons Than Dreamy Humans

Notes

16 Lightning

The Ego Machines Function in Textbook Fashion – and Start Wars

Notes

17 Politics

How to Trap States in a Cage

Notes

18 Matrix

‘How do you Create Men Like This?’

Notes

19 Mind’s eye

The Market-Conforming Democracy Boots Up

Notes

20 Coordination

In the ‘Twilight of Sovereignty’, Markets Give Power to the People

Notes

21 Big data

Number 2 is Flying in a Helicopter Above Our Heads

Notes

22 Subjugation

We are the Sum of Our Desires, and we Know What we Desire

Notes

Part II Optimization of the individual

23 The secret

Instructions for the Game of Life

Notes

24 Success

God Wants you to be Rich. Why Aren’t you?

Notes

25 Alchemists

Transform your Soul Into Gold, Because Work is Work on Oneself

Notes

26 Transmutation of the soul

Life as a Failed Experiment

Notes

27 Death dating

Creative Destruction and the Engineers’ Art

Notes

28 Re-engineering

The Disassembled Individual is a Goldmine

Notes

29 You

How the Essence of a Person is Read and Marketed

Notes

30 Mass delusions

Surplus, Wealth for All and the Knowledge Society

Notes

31 Ego

Killing the Puppets

Notes

Acknowledgements

Appendix

Short History of the Development of Artificial Agents in Stock Exchanges

Notes

References

Index of names

Guide

Cover

Table of Contents

Begin Reading

Pages

ii

iii

iv

vii

viii

ix

x

xi

xii

1

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

35

36

37

38

39

40

41

42

43

44

45

46

47

48

49

50

51

52

53

54

55

56

57

58

59

60

61

62

63

64

65

66

67

68

69

70

71

72

73

74

75

76

77

78

79

80

81

82

83

84

85

86

87

88

89

90

91

92

93

94

95

96

97

98

99

100

101

102

103

104

105

106

107

108

109

110

111

112

113

114

115

116

117

118

119

120

121

122

123

124

125

126

127

128

129

130

131

132

133

134

135

136

137

138

139

141

143

144

145

146

147

148

149

150

151

152

153

154

155

156

157

158

159

160

161

162

163

164

165

166

167

168

169

170

171

172

173

174

175

176

177

178

179

180

181

182

183

184

185

186

187

188

189

190

191

192

193

194

195

196

197

198

199

200

201

202

203

204

205

206

207

208

209

210

211

212

213

214

215

216

217

218

219

220

221

222

223

224

225

226

227

228

229

230

231

232

233

234

235

236

237

238

239

240

Maybe the target nowadays is not to discover what we are but to refuse what we are.

Michel Foucault

E G O

THE GAME OF LIFE

FRANK SCHIRRMACHER

TRANSLATED BY NICK SOMERS

polity

First published in German as Ego. Das Spiel des Lebens © Karl Blessing Verlag, a division of Verlagsgruppe Random House GmbH, Munich, Germany, 2013

This English edition © Polity Press, 2015

Polity Press65 Bridge StreetCambridge CB2 1UR, UK

Polity Press350 Main StreetMalden, MA 02148, USA

All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purpose of criticism and review, no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior permission of the publisher.

ISBN-13: 978-0-7456-8690-5

A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Schirrmacher, Frank, author.

[Ego. English]

Ego : the game of life / Frank Schirrmacher.

pages cm

First published in German as Ego : Das Spiel des Lebens, by Karl Blessing Verlag in 2013.

Includes bibliographical references and index.

ISBN 978-0-7456-8686-8 (hardcover : alk. paper) -- ISBN 0-7456-8686-9 (hardcover : alk. paper) 1. Egoism. 2. Economic man. 3. Philosophical anthropology. 4. Civilization, Modern--21st century--Psychological aspects. I. Title.

BJ1474.S35613 2015

128--dc23

2015010069

The publisher has used its best endeavours to ensure that the URLs for external websites referred to in this book are correct and active at the time of going to press. However, the publisher has no responsibility for the websites and can make no guarantee that a site will remain live or that the content is or will remain appropriate.

Every effort has been made to trace all copyright holders, but if any have been inadvertently overlooked the publisher will be pleased to include any necessary credits in any subsequent reprint or edition.

For further information on Polity, visit our website: politybooks.com

PREFACE

We have become incredibly uncomplicated, but unfortunately we ourselves don’t notice it. Why do we do what we do? Why do we love what we love? These questions are so complex that we are usually incapable of answering them ourselves. Nor do we realize that other people have long answered them for us.

Forget for a moment what you know about psychology, brain research or even from your own experience about the puzzle of our existence. Unnoticed by us, economists have made the workings of the mind of the modern individual their affair.

To simplify a hyper-complex world and speed up business transactions, a model has been developed behind the scenes that is changing our lives.

According to this model, life can be made much simpler and more profitable if we assume that people are interested only in themselves and their own personal advantage. This book looks at how this originally harmless model has become a trap, and how well this trap is disguised.

All trappers camouflage their traps. In the forest they can do so with leaves and with metal clamps hidden in the earth: artefacts that are made to appear part of their natural surroundings. Among humans the traps are camouflaged as natural laws – hence the statement: ‘People are selfish’, genetically and morally. Supported by modern calculating machines, an economic model has turned this thesis into a natural law. And we are beginning to feel it.

Many people in today’s world think that they have more liberties and freedom of choice than ever, and that they can ultimately accept or reject theories as they wish.

In reality they have not only unknowingly accepted them; they have long been living and working with them.

We are experiencing a new era of information capitalism. It has started to transform the world into a state of mind. It performs and plans great things. It seeks to read, control and sell thoughts; to predict, price and eliminate risks. Its brain is occupied relentlessly with finding out what people do, say, buy and what new moves they are planning. Wherever they encounter it, they are confronted by a system that always knows better. It deprives them of the right to conceive their surroundings differently from what they are. It claims that whatever they do is for their own advantage.

For information capitalism there is no such thing as irrational behaviour. In its eyes, friendship, loyalty and love all have rational reasons motivated by self-interest – hence the proliferation of ‘incentives’, rewards ranging from bonuses in Wall Street to virtual medals, awards and ‘likes’ conferred for the most private matters.

There are open games like chess, and hidden games like poker in which the players can’t see each other’s cards. The information economy is like a round of poker. Its world is one in which people don’t really say and do what they think, but everyone becomes transparent when it is assumed that they are acting egotistically. Hence this huge demand for information, this compulsion to dissimulate, to bluff and to leave false clues. Finance algorithms disguise share transactions to confuse lurking predatory algorithms, or else predatory algorithms feed other economic agents at the speed of light with false information to force up prices. People adopt false identities, create Facebook profiles for their personnel head or bank. Entire states send out false signals so as to confuse markets. It is a society in which people mistrust not only one another but also themselves. It has reached the stage where people accept that their education, experience and career do not mean what they thought they did.

The prospect of obtaining answers to questions that have not yet even been asked, the claim to know more about people than they do themselves, the predictions of what people want before they know it themselves, the offer to be a ‘friend’, are identical in structure to secret service surveillance algorithms that recognize crimes that the perpetrators themselves are perhaps not yet even aware of. The new economy uses machines and defines human relationships with the aid of mathematics. It loves the ‘prisoner’s dilemma’, a canonical example from game theory in which two people share the same fate but cannot communicate with one another and are offered the opportunity to gain an advantage at the expense of the other. Betrayal is not only foreseen but ‘the rationally sanctioned norm’.1

It would appear that people who come into contact with this idea change their behaviour. A view of the world which believes that behind every human action is the inevitable logic of self-interest is predestined to produce endless egoism.2 These days, everyone comes into contact with this world view. In an environment in which information, not only in stock exchanges but also at work, in communication and even in friendships, is organized by logical computing machines calculating according to the laws of personal profit-maximization, social values change at an astonishing speed.

Information capitalism questions people’s lives and identities, harnesses the real economy for its purposes and is now in the process of rewriting constitutional and international law.

It is not only individuals who are losing their sovereignty. The sovereign rights of European states and parliaments amputated by the current euro crisis are not examples of professional malpractice but part of the operative logic of information capitalism.

It has undermined human thought with a labyrinth of tunnels and shafts and it processes the raw material it extracts on machines that – depending on the desk they sit on – can wage wars, incite revolutions, create money, control people or send the latest holiday photos. It appears to be in a position to cut off entire nations overnight or under certain circumstances to give an individual who connects into it the power of a state. People are beginning to go underground with it in closed rooms with artificial light and to take the tunnels dug by it for their own thoughts.

A hidden trap must deceive all of the senses. In his Encyclopédie, Diderot recommends disguising the smell of iron, because experienced animals associate it with their destruction. A modern standard work on trapping animals describes in all innocence how this is done: ‘Entice the animal into the machine, be it with a bait or through its natural curiosity.’ According to Otto Mayr, it is no coincidence that for a long time the English words ‘engine’ and ‘machine’ had negative connotations of deviousness, trickery, conspiracy and even intrigue.3 The information capitalism machine is the computer, but the device itself is innocent. It depends solely on who has it in their hands and for what purpose they use it. Once human self-interest is reduced to a formula, it can be used to calculate the behaviour of an entire society.

It was Diderot who described ‘trapping’ – not the trap – as a ‘science’. The challenge is to capture creatures whom experience has made suspicious. They can be caught only by collecting and falsifying information. The trap must present the bait as easy prey. The bear, fox or wolf must be led to believe that it can gain an unexpected benefit. To do this, it is necessary ‘to study with great care the places to where the animals withdraw during the day, the places they spend the nights, and the paths they usually follow’.

The trap is also useless without the trapper’s strategy. The most successful trappers are those who think like the creature they are trapping; the most successful avoiders of traps are those who think like the trappers who wish to catch them. That is the ‘science’; it is pure mathematics and can be programmed by computers: during the Cold War, when it was invented, it was called ‘rational choice theory’ and given the harmless-sounding name ‘game theory’.

Driven psychologically by the fear that totalitarian systems like the Soviet Union disempowered people by claiming to know what was best for them, economists devised an alternative system in which individuals did only what was best for themselves. It became one of the most important strategic weapons in the Cold War, and through it the West scored a resounding victory in the superpower game.

As it turned out, however, that wasn’t the end but only the beginning. The superpower game was over, and the game could now be turned to individual societies. One of the architects of the great trap later admitted that the rules by which the new Game of Life is played need some getting used to. In order to win, you have to accept the idea that ‘the universe has singled you out to be its personal enemy’.4

A word in conclusion about the aim of this book. It was inspired by the crisis, not by its social but rather by its economic manifestations. The crisis is just a symptom. It shows the instability not only of markets but also of societies which, like markets and people, are organized like homo oeconomicus – in my eyes the first case of a system failure of the information economy.

The crisis we are dealing with today is not just about money, profit, the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy or the crisis in Europe. This, if you will, is just the simple side of the question, which is most easily susceptible to analysis. Who knows, perhaps it will be resolved, and people will go about their daily business again.

The information economy evaluates feelings, trust and social contacts as well as shares or goods, and for the first time in history it has the technical wherewithal to do it with increasing degrees of perfection. It is one thing to take for granted in a business transaction or auction that your counterparts will quite naturally look out for themselves and possibly pull a fast one on you. It is something else for social life itself to become increasingly like a business transaction or auction, a world of self-promotion according to completely transparent economic rules. In this world, mistrust, insinuation, bluff, diversionary tactics, have become the norm, be it only, as is often stated, ‘to reassure the market’. But they apply not only to states but to an even greater extent to individuals.

These rules are all written down somewhere. They are assumptions, auxiliary structures, models, attributing not mental but mathematical characteristics. One book starts with the quote ‘Populating economic models with “flesh-and-blood human beings” was never the objective of economists’, and then goes on to prove precisely the opposite.5 The models themselves have come alive. They are no longer mere instructions to be followed implicitly like a navigation device. They do much more: it is the models themselves that make individuals into the persons they describe. And they describe them, for all their self-imposed reservations, as egoists.

This book is based on a single thesis. It has been raised again recently by a few renegade economists, who call it ‘economic imperialism’. They mean by this that the theoretical models in economics hold sway over practically all other social sciences. (The most imperialistic economic theory was obviously Marxism.)

In our world we experience this imperialism as the economization of everything and everyone. It is no coincidence that bestsellers like Freakonomics (or the nudge theories of behavioural economists) are so successful. At their core, these books describe an everyday world that breaks down everything into self-interest anecdotes (‘Do you penalise parents for late pick-up from childcare and, if so, what is the response? Parents are even more negligent for low penalties, both because it is worth paying the cost and the low penalty falsely signals how little the moral cost is for transgressing norms’).6 However entertaining they are and however controversial the theories, their success shows that they are self-defence theories in a world which, translated entirely into economics, sees self-interest as the innermost core of rational behaviour.

But there is a high price to pay for this self-defence: many of the amusing suggestions, as Gerd Gigerenzer and Nathan Berg have shown in an eminent study of behaviour economics, conceal a neoclassical – or even a neoliberal – ideology.7 This applies not only to behaviour economics but also to all automated markets, from financial markets to the new social communication markets.

Economic imperialism forces us – even more so since the financial crisis – not to leave the field to a dominant school of Anglo-Saxon economists in particular. A whole world has seen that some of the models postulated as the truth in recent years have weaknesses. If this book looks at two of the most effective structural theories in information economics, namely rational choice theory and game theory, it does not mean that they are the only ones.8 They are, however, of outstanding importance to the story that this book relates: how individuals can have the feeling that the entire universe is in a conspiracy against them and how, after the end of the Cold War, a new cold war is opening up in the heart of societies.

Notes

1.

S.M. Amadae,

Rationalizing Capitalist Democracy: The Cold War Origins of Rational Choice Liberalism

, p. 295.

2.

Amadae,

Rationalizing Capitalist Democracy

, p. 296.

3.

Otto Mayr,

Authority, Liberty, and Automatic Machinery in Early Modern Europe

, p. 124.

4.

Ken Binmore,

Game Theory: A Very Short Introduction

, p. 31.

5.

Dimitris Milonakis and Ben Fine,

From Economics Imperialism to

Freakonomics: The Shifting Boundaries between Economics and Other Social Sciences

, p. 1.

6.

Milonakis and Fine,

From Economics Imperialism to Freakonomics

, p. 107.

7.

Nathan Berg and Gerd Gigerenzer, ‘As-If-Behavioural Economics: Neoclassical Economics in Disguise?’

8.

I am aware that I am simplifying the historical complexity. The new rationality was not inspired solely by game and rational choice theory. It was the product of countless and sometimes loosely connected disciplines: computer theory, statistics and cybernetics have gone their independent ways and are only marginally linked with game theory. It is true that Neumann’s work would have been inconceivable without Alan Turing’s computing machine and the resultant question of what is computable and what not. In ‘The Ontology of the Enemy: Norbert Wiener and the Cybernetic Vision’, for example, Peter Galison describes how in the Second World War the ‘rational’ enemy became a conceptual figure with all the characteristics that game theory later attributed to it.

PART IOPTIMIZATION OF THE GAME

1TRANCE

THE MILITARY SEEKS AN ANSWER TO THE QUESTION OF HOW ONE ACTS EGOTISTICALLY

It starts, like a story from The Twilight Zone, with a trance. We are in the first years of the Cold War. Somewhere in America, protected by metre-thick bombproof concrete and steel walls, sit highly trained people. They are members of the United States aerial surveillance units. They are gazing at radar screens.

The soldiers are looking for small blinking dots that appear occasionally on the screen. They register even the slightest movement; every signal could be a Russian aeroplane loaded with an atomic bomb. They have been told repeatedly that no job in the entire American armed forces is more vital.

Then inexplicable things happen. An air force officer, who has survived the Second World War without a scratch, manages to break his leg on the short journey from his screen to the coffee machine. Others nod off for a moment. Some are away answering queries. Then there is the artificial light, the underground doors and passages, the growing bunker mentality, and always the green circles of the radar screen: all this reinforces the sense of being inside a ‘hypnotic organism’.

‘It’s difficult to stay awake,’ admits a crew member, ‘when you’re sitting in a dark room staring at a radar screen day after day, week after week, always looking for a signal that needs a decision.’ And that’s fatal, because ‘a minute asleep could mean a city destroyed’, as a concerned visitor to the bunker wrote in 1955.1

A team of scientists – economists, psychologists and sociologists – alerted by the military tried to track the absences in the green-lit faces. And they finally realized that it was the computers, these vigilant machines, that were hypnotizing the men operating them.

This presented the researchers with an almost insoluble task: how to train soldiers to resist the hypnotic power of their own tools.

Every thirty seconds the men in the white coats scanned the soldiers’ faces with cameras controlled by punched cards. Every twenty minutes they photographed their screens, drew diagrams on their writing pads, in which they made notes every hour on the crew’s movements and the spatial distances between them – exactly the stuff of many a Hollywood science fiction or horror movie.

The scientists called these ‘psychodrama sessions’. The aim, however, was to describe the soldiers’ minds in mathematical terms. Not only were men operating machines, but machines were learning how to operate men.2 To do this, people had to learn how to become machine-readable. And in this way science fiction became reality, because for the first time machines recorded not only movements or time management but also human ‘values’ and feelings.3

It turned out that many soldiers regarded the radar screens as outsize telescopes or as a ‘window’ into the world. This looked like a place to start. They had to be taught that what they were seeing on the screen was a game in which the other player, the Soviet Union, would do anything to trick them. It was a question not just of registering a signal but of predicting at any given moment the next movements of the blinking dot, which could be the Soviet adversary.

Since the Russians had the atomic bomb and a single aeroplane had the destructive power of entire squadrons of aircraft, the need for completely new strategic thinking had become vital. In the paranoid atmosphere of the time (when people didn’t know what we now know in retrospect), when a surprise attack by the Soviet Union was an ever-present threat, the human relationship to information had to be reduced to a simple code: expect the worst. You don’t know, the crews were drilled, what the opponent plans, but you do know that its only aim is to trick you.

The mesmerizing green lights on the monitor didn’t display the ‘truth’ or the world as it was. They showed, as a contemporary report described it, a ‘poker face’.4 The soldier at the radar had to imagine himself and the screen as two poker players. It was a cut-throat game, as poker is often described. By seeing himself as a player in a poker game, the soldier was kept awake, stimulated, with his strategic intelligence honed.

The blinking dot could be a harmless commercial aircraft or a Russian aeroplane with a nuclear payload. The man at the machine had to understand that ‘poker face’ meant not spatial movements but strategic moves and could just as well be a bluff as the real thing.

So as not to fall into the trap, there was only one reliable assumption, one that worked well in economics, as the economists involved knew only too well: acting ‘rationally’ can only mean operating in one’s own interests. For strategic intelligence this meant that if people acted in a certain way, it had to be assumed that they were hiding something in order to win the Game of Life.

Fifty years later, the anthropologist Caitlin Zaloom, who worked for two years as a stock exchange trader in order to describe the fully automated trading world, made exactly the same observation. The traders have to train their attention completely on numbers, which are no longer something fixed and stable but turn into continuously changing real-time signals.5 Every transaction is a move in a game; all of the players think only of themselves; there are bluffs and surprise attacks, weapons of mass destruction and tactical, pinpoint weapons. The players are permanently screened, and decisions have to be made so quickly that they can only be done by computers.

Above all, however, it is the game theory models developed during the Cold War that are used by today’s hedge funds. Entire investment bank departments use computers and game theory to decipher the intentions of rival traders at breath-taking speed from a huge volume of data so as to adapt their own behaviour accordingly.

This would have come as no surprise to those who designed the mind of the new human. It was probably even their intention. It was not psychologists who devised the new ‘rational self-interest’ behaviour and conceptual models for the military, but economists, physicists and mathematicians. The economists were familiar with markets in which everyone sought their own advantage. Their strategies for an egotistical society were never limited solely to the military in the Cold War. The strategies were said to be universal and applicable wherever decisions were made – in poker, in business, at the stock exchange, in war.6

In 1950 the American sociologist David Riesman complained in his international bestseller The Lonely Crowd that in modern society individuals were becoming radar operators of their own life. No longer guided by their inner self but from outside, they could not help picking up signals from others and adapting their behaviour accordingly.7 Now the criticism was reversed: everything becomes logical when one recognizes that the world is a poker game and everyone wants to win.

It sounded very convincing. When the first information about this new theory was leaked, a lot of hype developed around it. In a few years RAND Corporation, the organization to which the scientists who analysed the radar crews belonged, developed under the cloak of military secrecy into the most powerful think tank in the United States. It was not just about the Soviet Union anymore. It was about everything.

The birth of this idea has been described as ‘a key transition in American intellectual history’.8 It is certainly one of the most underestimated. Only if we accept the premise that individuals always act out of self-interest can the entire complexity of human behaviour be translated into the language of mathematics. Formulae can be written, moves calculated, negotiations and compromises modelled and people trained to a new ‘rationality’, which they master automatically as if in a trance – an operation that is impossible if it is assumed that individuals have to be understood through their unique personal character.

A decisive factor in the worldwide breakthrough was the fact that these calculations could now be done at lightning speed and then also in real time. The first computers offered ingenious tools that were just waiting to be fed with the formulae for people. Calculating machines are bad at psychology but very good at computing profit maximization. Economists began to calculate the most complex decision situations with the aid of computers. With the financial support of the military, this was also tried out first of all on the Soviet Union.

Computers analysed the signals on radar screens and, as if in a military stock exchange, became better and better at predicting the Soviet opponent’s next moves. What is he doing? What is he planning? What is he hiding? But the Russians were just as paranoid. Very soon it became ‘What will he do if he knows that I know what he is planning?’ The computers educated the people working with them. They demonstrated how people should be thinking in the modern world. They provided constant examples. They merged so much with human thinking that soon no military strategist believed that it was possible to think any other way.

‘Learn to act rationally’ meant learning to think and act on the assumption that everyone is acting out of self-interest. The operation worked even with behaviour that appeared altruistic. One can puzzle for a long time as to why someone might give a complete stranger 10 euros (or why the Russians would launch a disarmament initiative). Only when it is realized, so the theory says, that even in this case the person is seeking an advantage is it possible to understand it.

Soon, however, this theory was not being restricted solely to armament and war strategies. It was not only a tool. It developed into a stealthy, decades-long training in egoism. The computer showed how astonishingly far it was possible to go when all calculations were based on this motivation. It was an innocent machine. But through the information fed into it, it evolved, as has been aptly pointed out, from a training system into an ‘indoctrination system’.9

No one suspected in the frosty 1950s that fifty years later, long after the disappearance of the Soviet Union, the idea of human behaviour born then would cause so much fear and terror in the world and would change social relations so fundamentally. What we are dealing with today is not the work of a few egotistical hedge fund managers or greedy investment bankers. They are just a symptom. In the cold years of the arms race – and not in the economic crises of the twenty-first century – a creature was let loose whose career did not really take off until the end of the Cold War.

Notes

1.

Sharon Ghamari-Tabrizi, ‘Cognitive and Perceptual Training in the Cold War Man-Machine System’, pp. 289–90.

2.

See George Dyson,

Darwin among the Machines

, p. 21.

3.

Ghamari-Tabrizi, ‘Cognitive and Perceptual Training in the Cold War Man-Machine System’, p. 289.

4.

Don Murray in a 1955 report on the first radar systems in which he described the ‘bluff’ of a non-identified aeroplane on its way to Los Angeles. See Ghamari-Tabrizi, ‘Cognitive and Perceptual Training in the Cold War Man-Machine System’, p. 270.

5.

Caitlin Zaloom,

Out of the Pits: Traders and Technology from Chicago to London

, pp. 136f.

6.

Fred Kaplan describes the division of labour between economists and mathematicians as follows: economists would ‘study the “utility functions” of consumers and the actual behaviour and values of various nations. The mathematicians, who certainly knew nothing of such things, could then incorporate their findings into the matrixes of game theory.’

The Wizards of Armageddon

, p. 67.

7.

David Riesman,

The Lonely Crowd: A Study of the Changing American Character

, p. 25. Cf. Ghamari-Tabrizi, ‘Cognitive and Perceptual Training in the Cold War Man-Machine System’, p. 271.

8.

For example, Amadae,

Rationalizing Capitalist Democracy

, p. 157.

9.

Ghamari-Tabrizi, ‘Cognitive and Perceptual Training in the Cold War Man-Machine System’, pp. 284f.

2GAME

ECONOMISTS GIVE AN ANSWER

The formula that everyone operates egotistically and tries to outsmart the next person was devised during the Cold War. There was a rationale behind the idea. The formula worked because at the time there were two world powers opposing one another, both with the atomic bomb and both capable of completely annihilating the other.

Economics had a long tradition of the self-serving man, homo oeconomicus, a kind of virtual doppelgänger used to explain what makes people tick. He was now hauled out of the basement again, where he had been gathering dust. Previously, homo oeconomicus had led something of a remote and purely academic life. There were even formulae for him, some dating from the nineteenth century.

This is not the place to recount the two-hundred-year history of homo oeconomicus. It would be incorrect, however, to assume that he was simply let loose on the world from the outset as a profit-seeking monster – even if he infiltrated early modern English literature in particular in that guise.1 As a being who was no longer to be explained by way of his diffuse passions but rather through his uncompromising interests (possibly including concepts such as freedom), homo oeconomicus was always an Enlightenment figure as well, and to a certain extent, as Habermas’s student Axel Honneth has shown, he could even be called a founding idea of the ‘Left’.2 He is a textbook figure, and clever economists point out ceaselessly that he should never be more than that: an assumption that enables us not only to better explain people and their preferences but also to design social contracts that have the advantage of not aiming for fine-sounding – although just as insubstantial – values such as beauty, truth and goodness.

And yet this is only one side of the story, and the good side at that. The bad side was summed up in a single sentence in 2008 by Lynn A. Stout, professor of law at Cornell University and an expert in corporate governance and finance market regulation familiar with the financial crises of the last few years: ‘Homo oeconomicus is a sociopath.’3

Countless authors, including many economists, have shown recently that the assumptions on which homo oeconomicus are based do not take sufficient account of the diversity of the human psyche and human society.4 This book nevertheless claims that the person we are calling Number 2 here has been brought to life in the last few years and has become something that the responsible side of his creators never wanted.

The reasons for this are by no means of a purely ‘economic’ nature. They have to do with the fact that modern individuals no longer know exactly what their identity is, or whether they have one, many, or none at all. Contemporary philosophies are of no help to them but have rather confirmed the trend. As a result, there has automatically been less resistance to this simplified model, which until the middle of the last century lived to a certain extent as well from its contrast with the real person.

It was the first great victory of ‘economic imperialism’, which turned everything into economics; but it was a victory because the opposition dissolved. To that extent, economists cannot be blamed for occupying a space given up by others. Subjectivity or individuality was replaced by preferences (which come from outside and do not therefore need to be explained) and the desire for utility maximization.5 Nothing else was needed anymore. As Michel Foucault put it, homo oeconomicus was not just an economic but also a political being and he had the advantage in the eyes of authority that he was ‘eminently governable’.6

This on its own would not have been sufficient to bring Number 2 to life. Without the computer, without the electronic spark jumping between machine and man, he would still have remained only a model; a theory with the advantage (unlike Marxism) that it was nothing else but that.

‘After the fall’ is the way the economist and philosopher John B. Davis, not without pathos, describes this expulsion from a noncommittal Garden of Eden.7 It took place in two stages: initially through the emergence of the first computers in the military and economic landscape of the 1950s, and then (with consequences greater than the invention of the steam engine) through the triumph of the ‘democratized’ computer in mass markets since the early 1980s. The fusion of science and scientists and indeed entire societies with their technologies, the creation of man–machine composites, whether they are called androids or cyborgs, will be a recurrent subject in this book. A revision of the image of the individual in the light of this fusion took place simultaneously in all disciplines, and ironically this revision often ended up with a model that economists had already categorized and conceived as homo oeconomicus. Cognitive sciences, for example, which began to play an important role in the post-war era, were no longer interested in the humanization of the machine but, as Jean-Pierre Dupuy formulated it, in the mechanization of the mind.8 In the famous words of Martin Heidegger, cybernetics, the first science to merge with the computer, replaced philosophy.

Science not only uses technologies as tools to discover or change something. More than that, it discovers and systematically changes whatever the tools enable it to. The ability to calculate a person’s preferences – and soon those of an entire society, as appears likely as we approach the era of big data – is possible in real time only when there are tools available that allow this.9

Merely by using a calculator, anyone can intuitively grasp the notion that the brain is like a calculator and that mental processes are thus the calculations of a biological computer – an idea that in the 1950s was still not readily accepted.

This is all that Number 2 had ever claimed for himself. The rational individual is a calculating machine. He can be reduced to what he wants and chooses egotistically, his so-called preferences, and they can be calculated mathematically. The formalization of economics through mathematical formulae after the Second World War (Davis calls it an ‘arms race’ among economists for prestige and influence) indeed makes it possible for individuals to be seen as nothing more than ‘mathematical objects’.10

Every economist would admit that assumptions about people are simplifications – so radical are these simplifications, in fact, that, as has been rightly pointed out, ‘the individual of mainstream economics is pared down to a point of nothingness, excepting the possession of automaton-like choice’.11 But what if reality becomes precisely this automaton? What if the world turns increasingly into a great machine that operates in this very manner? The problem is not the simplified models. The problem is that we are witnessing a radical change, in which these models encode reality and become real themselves in this way. And not only that: they decide what is rational and what is not. If this is too abstract, just ask yourself what ‘preferences’ Google or Facebook decides for you, or – much more dramatically and topical – what stock exchange algorithms describe the trader’s preferences. The assumptions made by Number 2 – when reading an e-book, with ‘smart’ appliances, in finance markets, in political life – are already implanted. They are, as Michael Callon puts it, ‘performative’; they create the reality they model.12

This imperialist victory has antecedents directly connected with the Cold War.

It is self-evident that everyone wants to win rather than lose in markets, and it is trivial to say that no one should be reproached for wanting to do business. The new idea was that now only self-interested motivation counted and that an entire society was to be modelled in its image. The tacit agreement that people in reality are more diverse, richer, more contradictory and more moral than the theory claimed faded in the 1950s and was soon forgotten by some economists. It was now regarded as quite reasonable and in no way morally objectionable to act as the theory demanded.

In fact, for quite understandable reasons, morality did not play a major role at all. The explanation is obvious: during the Cold War it would have been fatally imprudent in this game to want to be anything other than a winner or to consider anything other than personal advantage. But if this was reasonable in a military setting, it was not limited to that setting. The models were designed for dealing not only with the opponent but also with the relationship of individuals with the world.

Many of the economists working in the 1950s at RAND Corporation or advising the military belonged to the so-called ‘neoclassical’ school based at the University of Chicago, which for some time had been teaching in economics that people are egotistical and that markets are truth machines. Now they saw the opportunity to turn a mere assertion into a natural law.

They started writing formulae and algorithms, and the formulae in turn could be understood by computers. That alone was new. Previously – contrary to what is thought today – the social sciences frowned on the idea of casting human behaviour into mathematical moulds. But if it was assumed that people sought their own advantage, their behaviour could be described mathematically.

These often ingenious economists became experts not only in automating the military but also in automating markets and the people in these markets. They were pioneers in a world that was still half a century away from one in which every person would be linked to computers and markets. But all their formulae could be understood and processed by computers.

They invented something they called ‘game theory’. And with the aid of this invention they introduced this cognitive model into our Game of Life. After the Cold War many of the economists with RAND Corporation won Nobel Prizes for economics. It was the culmination of a massive undertaking that transferred the logic of the Cold War to civil society. In the end, in the first decade of the twenty-first century, the ego model had indeed become a natural law. And no one can doubt that it functioned better than all the vague supra-individual value ideologies with their supposed mandatory ethical roles that give rise to the murderous collectivism (or racism) that had been allowed to evolve in the twentieth century. The entire global organism, wrote the senior leader writer of The New Yorker following 9/11, ‘is based on a kind of basic faith – the unsentimental expectation that people, both individuals and society as a whole, act more or less through rational self-interest’.13

In the era of ‘rational machines’, however, we are beginning to realize that this rationality comes at a cost. And to date, with few exceptions, the world has been in a trance and is barely aware that these economists have changed the human soul more incisively than any psychology.

They didn’t build any weapons, produce any goods or solder any processors, but instead essentially wrote the programs for the three great machines that continue to define our world: the military, the market and the computer. They began where people are most easily seduced: with the opportunity to make a profit – not only in the great game of the Cold War, but also in life.

From the mid-1950s, the military in the Cold War sought with the aid of the computer to create a rational, predictable, indefatigable substitute for man, an ‘agent’ who was interested only in his own survival and who could assess both the risk of an attack and also the best opportunity for a strike.

And as subsequent years were to prove, these were the same qualities that the new economic markets wanted: a person who sought to make profits, could calculate risks and knew when to strike at an auction.

But the most disruptive factor when calculating the future is people themselves. They are an ever-changing risk. They not only fall asleep sometimes at work, but are also refractory and contradictory, play their cards close to their chests, and have so many useless and unreasonable things in their heads that they upset all calculations.

For centuries, efforts had been made to find out what makes people tick, and all of these efforts – be they by soothsayers, philosophers or psychologists – ultimately failed. So how did economists, of all people, manage to devise a formula for human unpredictability?

Their brilliant idea was no longer to ask what makes people tick but how